When real household spending fell by 4.6% in April 2014 it was cause for concern. That was the first month after the tax hike hit and the decline in spending was much larger than anticipated (by economists, at least). Despite the heavy toll, Bank of Japan officials remained (outwardly) wholly unconcerned over what was believed a minor setback on the road to raging inflationary success. With so much “stimulus”, including of the fiscal kind, there was no way Japan’s economy would fail to respond.

While spending had declined, “inflation” had ticked to its highest level since February 1991.

Japanese consumer prices showed that inflation picked up in April [2014], excluding the sales tax increase that started at the beginning of the month, government data showed Friday. The data was a welcome sign in the central bank’s battle to increase inflation to 2 percent.

Economists were overjoyed if somewhat cautious.

“Consumer spending has declined as expected in April, but this is likely to be minor blip and will not affect the ongoing recovery,” Martin Schulz, of Fujitsu Research Institute told the BBC.

 

“Both consumer spending and retail sales will start rising in the latter half of the year.”

By August 2014, Bank of Japan Governor Haruhiko Kuroda was quite confident and positive despite weakness in spending that persisted well beyond April 2014 (May was actually much worse).

In April last year [2013], the Bank of Japan introduced quantitative and qualitative monetary easing (QQE) to achieve the price stability target of 2 percent at the earliest possible time, with a time horizon of about two years. The last time I addressed you here was only a year ago. At that time, I mentioned that there was a positive turnaround in three areas since the introduction of QQE: in financial conditions, expectations, and economic activity and prices. Since then, QQE has been steadily having its intended effects, and the positive turnaround in the three areas has continued. Japan’s economy has been on a path suggesting that the 2 percent price stability target will be achieved as expected.

Since that speech, the Bank of Japan raised its QQE component to ¥80 trillion yen annually and now has implemented a tiered negative interest rate regime. Household spending for December 2015, the latest figures released, fell by 4.4% in real terms year-over-year; -4.2% nominally. That was practically the same level that shocked economists almost two years ago and yet Japan is still facing the same economic hole, only extensively widened. There was no tax hike to blame nor even “inflation” itself as despite all proclamations issued over the intervening twenty months the calculated “inflation” rate is practically zero once again. All that is left is the admissions for absolute failure of the entire project, which arouses nothing of suspicion in the media or mainstream.

Instead, negative interest rates are treated, at least initially, as some kind of hope as if any different than the undeniably massive QQE that was perpetrated upon the poor Japanese people. The scorecard registers a full knock-out; the Bank of Japan under QQE/QE10 has increased the level of bank reserves by +339% since March 2013; total real household income over that same period is -7.1%.

ABOOK Feb 2016 Japan Devastation QEs

A few percent in decline is a disaster; -7.1% skews beyond written description. And that isn’t the worst of it as the true cost is measured not just in declining national income or spending but in the time period rendered useless (lost compounding is the greatest cost). Time and time again (pun intended), economists tell us that there needs to be this kind of negative factor or negative redistribution effects “necessary” to complete the recovery agenda. QQE was started in April 2013, only a few months shy of three years ago. The yen started depreciating in October 2012.

With monetarism there is no “transitory” only the desperate wake of economic destruction. The Japanese economy has only grown poorer for which Japanese households have paid for with their own poverty. In other words, the true foundation of their economy has been rapidly undermined by the intensive monetarism, a relationship that bears out repeatedly.

ABOOK Feb 2016 Japan Devastation HH Spending ABOOK Feb 2016 Japan Devastation HH Income ABOOK Feb 2016 Japan Devastation HH DPI

BoJ officials and economists keep saying that businesses will respond via inflation expectations by offering more wage gains. And in some cases they appear to; “special cash earnings” jumped by 25.2% in May 2015 and 18.2% last October. Those months, however, are limited in their wage impacts. The key months for Japanese income are June and December (more the latter). Special cash earnings fell 6.7% in June 2015 and were down 0.4% in December.

That means real wages in the all-important December month for 2015 were 2.8% less than December 2013 and 4.1% less than December 2012.

ABOOK Feb 2016 Japan Devastation Real Wages Longer

 

Meanwhile, the Ministry of Finance estimates that total labor expended in Japan continues to sink. Total hours worked declined again in December for the fourth straight month; non-scheduled aggregate hours worked, overtime essentially, has fallen for eleven consecutive months dating back to last January.

ABOOK Feb 2016 Japan Devastation Hours Worked

Economists say of Japan (as the US) that this is demographics but the transition could not be clearer. The population did not suddenly start to decline in October 2012 when the yen started to. Labor utilization seems to have hit a persistent downdraft starting right at that point entirely different than even the years before and after the tsunami. In other words, QQE has left a permanent scar upon the Japanese economy, in its very foundation, far worse than anything unleashed by Mother Nature.

Again, this experiment has run almost three full years and there is only more evidence of further alarming decline balanced against absolutely nothing that would suggest central banks have any idea what they are doing. They stick to the script of expectations regardless of how little it actually happens. Not even “inflation” has cooperated even though the yen has; which, in the twisted sense of monetarism is actually a very small blessing for the Japanese people. It bears repeating: in December 2015 nominal household spending in Japan fell by 4.2%; nominal income by 2.7%. Neither of those declines is out of line for the Japanese economy after nearly three years of negative redistribution.

Is it any wonder BoJ and central bankers want to try something else, not something actually different just something, anything that might be free of this negative and harmful association? The BoJ has increased the level of “base money” in Japan by ¥184 trillion (thru the end of January 2016) via QQE/QE10 in what was supposed to by sheer size alone leave no doubt of its power and vigor. There are no doubts, anymore, which is precisely Kuroda’s problem. Recovery in Japan starts when it no longer is.